翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ John A. Hartell
・ John A. Hartford Foundation
・ John A. Hartle
・ John A. Harts
・ John A. Hartwell
・ John A. Hasecoster
・ John A. Hastings
・ John A. Hawkins (linguist)
・ John A. Hawkins (New York)
・ John A. Hay
・ John A. Heffern
・ John A. Hefferon
・ John A. Hennessy
・ John A. Hiigli
・ John A. Hill
John A. Hobson
・ John A. Holm
・ John A. Hostetler
・ John A. Houston
・ John A. Hull
・ John A. Humphrey
・ John A. Huntsman
・ John A. Jane
・ John A. Jenkins
・ John A. Johnson
・ John A. Johnson (politician)
・ John A. Kaneb
・ John A. Kasson
・ John A. Kay
・ John A. Keith


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

John A. Hobson : ウィキペディア英語版
John A. Hobson


John Atkinson Hobson (commonly known as John A. Hobson or J. A. Hobson; 6 July 1858 – 1 April 1940), was an English economist, social scientist and critic of imperialism, widely popular as a lecturer and writer.
==Life==
Hobson was born in Derby,〔John A. Hobson: Critical assessment of leading Economists. Edited by Robert D. and John C. Wood. 2003 Taylor and Francis. ISBN 0-415-31066-0 p. 137〕 the son of William Hobson, "a rather prosperous newspaper proprietor",〔Hobson, Lenin and anti-Imperialism , presented by Tristram Hunt, BBC Radio 3, 6 March 2011〕 and Josephine Atkinson. He was the brother of the mathematician Ernest William Hobson. He studied at Derby School and Lincoln College, Oxford, afterwards teaching classics and English literature at schools in Faversham and Exeter.
When Hobson relocated to London during 1887, England was in the midst of a major economic depression. While classical economics was at a loss to explain the vicious business cycles, London had many societies that proposed alternatives. While living in London, Hobson was exposed to the Social Democrats and Henry Mayers Hyndman, Christian Socialists, and Henry George's Single-tax system. He befriended several of the prominent Fabians who would initiate the London School of Economics, some of whom he had known at Oxford. However, none of these groups proved persuasive enough for Hobson; rather it was his collaboration with a friend, the famous businessman and mountain climber Albert F. Mummery, that would produce Hobson's contribution to economics: the theory of underconsumption. First described by Mummery and Hobson in the 1889 book ''Physiology of Industry'', underconsumption was a scathing criticism of Say's law and classical economics' emphasis on thrift. The forwardness of the book's conclusions discredited Hobson among the professional economics community. Ultimately he was excluded from the academic community.
During the very late 19th century his notable works included ''Problems of Poverty'' (1891), ''Evolution of Modern Capitalism ''(1894), ''Problem of the Unemployed'' (1896) and ''John Ruskin: Social Reformer'' (1898). They developed Hobson's famous critique of the classical theory of rent and his proposed generalization anticipated the Neoclassical "marginal productivity" theory of distribution.
Soon after this period Hobson was recruited by the editor of the newspaper The ''Manchester Guardian'' to be their South African correspondent. During his coverage of the Second Boer War, Hobson began to form the idea that imperialism was the direct result of the expanding forces of modern capitalism. He believed the mine owners, with Cecil Rhodes, who wanted control of the Transvaal, in the vanguard, were manipulating the British into fighting the Boers so that they could maximize their profits from mining.〔Hobson, Lenin and anti-Imperialism, Radio 3, 6 March 2011〕 His return to England was marked by his strong condemnation of the conflict.
His publications during the next few years demonstrated an exploration of the associations between imperialism and international conflict. These works included ''War in South Africa'' (1900) and ''Psychology of Jingoism'' (1901). In what is arguably his magnum opus, ''Imperialism'' (1902), he espoused the opinion that imperial expansion is driven by a search for new markets and investment opportunities overseas. ''Imperialism'' gained Hobson an international reputation, and influenced such notable people as Vladimir Lenin and Leon Trotsky, and Hannah Arendt's ''The Origins of Totalitarianism'' (1951).
Hobson wrote for several other journals before writing his next major work, ''The Industrial System'' (1909). In this tract he argued that maldistribution of income resulted, through oversaving and underconsumption, in unemployment and that the remedy was in eradicating the "surplus" by the redistribution of income by taxation and the nationalization of monopolies.
Hobson's opposition to the First World War caused him to join the Union of Democratic Control. His advocacy for the formation of a world political body to prevent wars can be found clearly in his piece ''Towards International Government'' (1914). However, he was staunchly opposed to the League of Nations.
During 1919 Hobson joined the Independent Labour Party. This was soon followed by writings for socialist publications such as the ''New Leader'', the ''Socialist Review'' and the ''New Statesman''. During this period it became clear that Hobson favoured capitalist reformation over communist revolution. He was a notable critic of the Labour Government of 1929.
During the later years of his life, Hobson published his autobiography, ''Confessions of an Economic Heretic'' (1938).

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「John A. Hobson」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.